Question: Does the so-called ‘Beijing Consensus’ present a meaningful
‘model’ or blueprint for development?
Optimo: It does, despite the alleged lack of
success of the model in China.
In his last post, Pessimo presented, in
a very clear fashion, the three theorems that characterize the so-called
Beijing Consensus, as defined by Ramo. He then criticized these three theorems
by raising two kinds of objections. One is that some of these theorems are
wrong or have unrealistic assumptions. The other objection is that China, which
was supposed to be an illustrative case for such theorems, has failed to
successfully achieve any of the goals set up by the model.
The
first type of criticism is far stronger than the second type. The Chinese
failure in successfully following or implementing the model may illustrate
problems in the model, but it says little about the overall potential of the
model to provide meaningful guidance to other countries. Thus, most of my
response will be focused on the first type of objection, the one that questions
the basic assumptions of the model.
Let’s
start with innovation (and given the length of my response I will leave the
other two theorems for future posts).
Pessimo is skeptical of the possibility of
creating “and sustaining capacity for leading edge innovation is virtually
impossible in the developing world”. To support this idea he mentions that many
attempts to create industrial parks modeled after “those that have promoted
leading-edge innovation in Taiwan and South Korea have been unsuccessful”. If I
understand this correctly, there seems to be an inherent contradiction in the
argument here: if “innovation is virtually impossible in the developing world”,
how can we explain that countries like Taiwan and South Korea managed to successfully
create innovative industrial parks? Should they not be classified as developing
countries? Assuming they were developing countries at the time these innovations
took place, maybe we can start by toning down the criticism and assume
that innovation is not “virtually impossible” but perhaps “less likely to
happen” in the developing world?
The
fact that some developing countries have failed at producing innovation alone
is not a reason to disprove the model. The question that need to be answered is
why these countries have failed. This is exactly the point in which my
disagreement with Pessimo becomes
very clear. To explain the failed attempts to set up “ledging-edge” or
“bleeding-edge” innovation, Pessimo
argues that a series of pre-determined economic factors that are directly
associated with the geographical conditions of the country (the so called
agglomeration effects) tend to favor developed nations as the locus for such
innovation. This would require a country to “be lucky” enough to be in the
right place at the right time in order to develop. I do not subscribe to this
explanation, let alone to its deterministic tone.
Innovation
requires a variety of factors to take place, but one of the most cited studies
to explain the capacity of Taiwan and South Korea to produce innovation is the
idea of “Embedded Autonomy”, developed by Peter Evans. The argument has two
parts. One is that the state has an important role to play in promoting
innovation. Thus, while innovation is not determined by geographic factors
alone, it is also not determined by the individual assumptions of the rational
actor model either. In other words, institutions matter. The second element is
the assumption that a particular type of state is required to promote such
innovation. According to Evans, the state’s capacity to produce innovation
requires a combination of the “autonomy” prescribed by the Weberian
bureaucratic model, while at the same time requiring the cooperation of private
actors that can only be obtained if the state in “embedded” in society. This “embedded
autonomy” is a “contradictory balance” that is hard to find. Moreover, Evans
acknowledges that there is more than one way for a state to be embedded in
society, as the contrasting examples of Taiwan and South Korea show.
Nevertheless, some form of embedded autonomy is a requirement for innovation to
take place.
The
best example to support Evan’s thesis and challenge the idea of agglomeration
effects is Brazil. As Evans shows, Brazil has not developed a fully functional
developmental state like Korea and Taiwan. Instead, the country has
mostly a dysfunctional bureaucracy, except for a few departments that are often
described as “pockets of efficiency”. When a pocket of efficiency manages to have
the required “embedded autonomy”, innovation becomes feasible. The automotive
sector in the 1960s and 1970s is one example. In contrast, Brazil’s massive
failure in producing innovation in information technology illustrates that a
country may be able to innovate in some sectors by not in others, depending on
the institutions governing each of these sectors.
Evans’
argument was recently by revised by him and by others. While the revisions do not reject the two basic premises of the
argument (the importance of the state, and the need for embedded autonomy), Evans’own revisions indicate that the relevant social relations supporting embeddedness
are now broader (i.e. it involves a larger set of actors). Others, in turn,
have emphasized the importance of focusing on processes, rather than outcomes
as exemplified by the most recent literature on industrial policy (e.g. see this piece
by Rodrik). Brazil again offers an example of this type of arrangement with the
innovations in the agricultural sector promoted by the Brazilian Corporation
for Agricultural Research, EMBRAPA.
In
addition to disagreeing with Pessimo’s argument
that innovation is “almost impossible” in developing countries due to
agglomeration effects, I also want to challenge his interpretation of the first
theorem of Ramo’s articulation of the Beijing Consensus. Pessimo seems to assume that the innovation needs to take place in
the developing world in order to promote development. I am not sure this is
what Ramo meant. The question that Ramo asks is what kind of technology should
these countries use to “start development”. His answer to this question is that
“bleeding-edge innovation” (rather than trailing-edge technology) that can
“create change that moves faster than the problems change creates” is more
likely to promote development. Where the technology is coming from, however, is
not clear -- not in the excerpt in Pessimo’s
post, at least.
There
is at least one example that may suggest that the technology can come from the
developed world and still benefit developing countries. Mobile banking in African nations
revolutionized financial transactions in the continent, allowing money
transfers from one cellphone to another without the intermediation of a
financial institution. This innovation builds upon a bleeding-edge technology
(mobile telephony) created in developed countries to bring change to another industry: banking in developing nations.
My
point here is that Pessimo’s argument
that innovation can only happen in developed countries seems to assume that
there is a linear process of innovation, and developing countries are playing
catch-up. If we abandon this premise, we can see that there is not a leader and
a follower, but there are instead multiple paths. Indeed, mobile banking in
Africa is the case in point. This is a particularly important innovation in a
region in which levels of literacy are low and the presence of financial
institutions outside large urban centers is scarce. So, the innovation is not
relevant to developed nations or even to middle-income countries, such as
Brazil and Mexico. But it has been quite relevant in the African context.
Another
important question is what kind of technological innovations can be classified
as bleeding-edge. One response is to say that it needs to be bleeding-edge from
a scientific standpoint. But I wonder if we should also include here the fact
that adopting bleeding-edge innovation and making not so bleeding-edge
modifications on it could generate relevant social changes. So, we do not need
to talk about ultra revolutionary scientific ideas, akin to inventing the laser
technology. Sometimes, some marginal modification in existing products can
generate quite significant results. One example is the slightly modified system
for public buses that has shown significant results. The so-called bus-rapid-transit
(BRT) requires less investment than subways, and is able to transport a higher
number of passengers than a regular bus system. The changes are the payment
system outside the buses, dedicated lanes and a faster entry-exit system in the
buses (which are at the same level of the boarding platform). As a result, it
is a great option for developing countries. Indeed, the system has been widely
adopted in Latin America and has already made inroads in China and India. This may
not be a “bleeding-edge” or “ledging-edge” innovation from a scientific
standpoint, but it has generated “bleeding-edge” innovations in public
transportation systems. If we consider the impact it has had in the lives of
millions of people, this could be considered the type of technological
innovation that may promote development.
The
last point I want to make is regarding the idea that technological innovation
will promote development as long as it “moves faster than the problems change
creates”. Pessimo questions what does
that mean. I think it means that dynamic innovation is better than slow moving
one (coming from outside or inside). As a particular technology becomes
widespread and settled, it creates a series of self-reinforcing mechanisms that
make it hard to move away from it, even if there is superior technology
available. The cautionary tale of the QWERTY keyboard is probably the most
cited example of this problem.
I
think this is enough to start the conversation. My comments on the other two
theorems will be coming next week.
No comments:
Post a Comment